M  A  S  I   

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

M A N A G E R I A L   R A T I O S

 

 

by

 

 

H A N S   J E S S E N

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

The Technical University of Denmark

November 1982

AMT Publication DI.82.85-A

.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

ABSTRACT

 

In order to determine managerial ratios as mathematical analytical functions of time there has been developed a graphical model of a firm. This model shows the physical relationship between fundamental principles of bookkee- ping, operating statements and managerial economics. The model is the structural basis of the determination of the mathematical analytical functions for management.

 

The analytical background of traditional ratio techniqu- es, including, Bela Gold lit. 40 and the Dupont pyramid, is described by means of a new developed general manage-rial ratio funktion.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- I -

 

CONTENTS

                                                                  Page

             Sumary                                                  V

             Preface                                                VI

Part A:

CHAPTER A

 

1.           An analytical business model                            1 

1.1.         Introduction                                            1

1.1.1.       S. Eilon's model                                        1

1.1.1.1.     Functional relationships and assumptions                3

1.1.1.1.1.   Change in the cost structure                            7

1.1.1.1.2.   Change in the earnings structure                       13

1.1.2.       Assessment of S. Eilon's model                         18

 

Part B:

CHAPTER_B

 

2.           An analytical graphical business model                 20

2.1.         Activity parameters                                    20

2.1.1.       Sales                                                  20

2.1.2.       Purchases                                              20

2.1.3.       Inventories                                            22

2.2.         Payment parameters, operations    

2.2.1.       Sales                                                  22

2.2.2.       Purchases                                              23

2.3.         Market parameters, sales                               23

2.3.1.       Cash sales ratio q                                     23

2.3.2.      The price p                                            24

2.3.3.       Debit time dD                                          24

2.4.         Market parameters, purchases                           25

2.4.l.       Cash purchases ratio  e                                25

2.4.2.       The price q1 of raw materials                           26

2.4.3.      The price q2 of labor hours                             26

2.4.4        Credit time  dK                                         27

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

- II -

 

3.1.         Income statement                                       28

3.1.1.      Sales of goods                                         28

3.1.2.      Costs                                                  29

3.1.2.1.    Inventories, additions (with signs)                    30

3.1.3.       Resource consumption (incl. F'i,1)                      33

3.1.4.      Operating profit (before interest and deprec.)         33

3.1.5.      Operating profit incl. inventory deprec.               33

 

 

4.1.         Chanqe in liquidity (operations)                       35

 

5.1.         Cash balance                                           36

5.2.         Bank loans                                             36

5.3.         Loans (long-term)                                      37

 

6.1.         Investment (in fixed capital)                          38

 

7.1.         Depreciation (for tax purposes)                        39

 

8.1.         Interest (for tax purposes)                            40

     

9.1.         Tax pavments                                           4O

     

10.1.        Principal ratios                                       41

10.1.1.     Operating profit 0'(t)                                  41

10.1.2.     Change in liquidity l'(t)                               42

10.1.3.     Working capital K(t)                                   43

10.1.4.      Contribution ratio DG(t)                               43

10.1.5.     Depreciation                                           44

10.1.6.      Interest r'BL(t)                                         44

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- III -

 

CHAPTER C

 

11.          An analytical mathematical businessmodel               45

11.1.        Physical and financial functions i the operating

                                                         system     45

11.1.1.      Sales                                                  45

11.1.2.      Inventories                                            46

11.1.3.      Output                                                 50

l1.1.4.      Sales, ingoing payments                                50

11.1.5.      Purchases, outgoing payments                           51

11.1.6.      Change in liquidity                                    52

11.2.        Capital tied up in the operating system                52

11.2.1.      Trade accounts receivable                              52

11.2.2.      Trade accounts payable                                 53

11.2.3.      Raw materials invefitory                               53

11.2.4.      Finished goods inventory                               54

11.2.5.      Working capital (tied up in the operating system       54

 

12.1.        Operatinq profit (for accountinq purposes)             55

12.2.        Operating profit (computed on the basis of Fig. 2.1.)  56

12.2.1.      Operating profit incl. inventory depreciation          58

12.3.1.      Bank loans                                             59

12.3.2.      Loans (long term)                                      60

12.3.3.     Investments                                            60

12.4.1.      Interest payments                                      61

12.4.2.      Depreciation                                           61

12.4.3.      Tax payments                                           61

12.4.4.      Cash flow released                                     62

12.4.4.1.   Interest relative                                      63

12.4.4.2.   Depreciation relative                                  63

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- IV -

 

13.1.        Traditional ratios                                     64

13.1.1       Contribution ratio                                     64

13.1.2.      Profit ratio                                           64

13.1.3.      Break-even sales                                       64

13.1.4.      Margin of safety                                       65

13.1.5.      Applications, examples                                 65

13.2.        Dupont pyramid                                         66

13.2.1       Ratio mathematics, general                             68

 

CONCLUSION                                                          7O

 

BIBLIOGRAPHY                                                        72

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- V -

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

SUMMARY

 

For the determination of ratios as analytical mathematical functions of time a graphical model of a firm has been developed. This model is a graphical representation of the relationships between fundamental aspects of the firm relating to book-keeping (records), accounting and managerial economics. The model forms the basis of the following deve- lopment of analytical mathematical functions. The mathematical back-ground of traditional ratio techniques, including Bela Gold lit. 40 and the Dupont pyramid, is shown through the development of a general ratio function.

 

Lyngby, November 1982

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

- VI -

 

 

PREFACE

 

The existing literature on accountancy and managerial economics has ma- de several attempts to improve the theoretical basis in order to provide management with a better understanding of business management possibili- ties.

 

In lit. 20, Albert Danielsson is dealing solely with purely analytical

aspects in relation to costs of production, and he has in that connec- tion developed symbolic flow charts for analysis purposes. This work seems to be of a very special character and not suited for overall ma- nagement purposes where the firm is to be seen as a whole. Links to inventories and the market are, for instance, missing.

 

Bela Gold, lit. 40, attempts to generalise accounting ratios in a tech-nical structure which includes managerial ratios. This technique seems to be very practicable but only for partial global business analyses. In this thesis a theoretical analysis of general ratios will be made, in-cluding the Dupont pyramid and including, in particular, Bela Gold's ratio technique.

 

J. W. Forrester, lit. 37, provides with his special representation

technique based on computer technology an excellent basis for analy- sing company behavlour. It gives, in a certain degree, a good insight into the behavlour of a firm in situations with different external and internal influences. Also here a fundamental mathematical model for purely analytical purposes is missing.

 

Dan Ahlmark, lit. 1, stresses the necessity of developing an analysis

model of the business which makes it possible to consider the current

integrated process, production, investment, financing activities of the business. To illustrate this need, an extensive empirical business ana- lysis is made, using generally known simulation techniques.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

-  VII -

 

Finn C. Sørensen, lit. 97, finds in his review of traditional accoun-

ting methods that a model should be developed for man agement which is

suitable for illustrating general matters in the firm, i.e. form the

basis of an actual managerial audit. By this is meant an examination of activities and matters underlying the financial/accounting report.

 

Samuel Eilon, lit. 30, attempts with his mathematical model to compute

the rate of return as a function of general business parameters, using, among other things, a symbolic graphical representation technique to de-scribe the inter relationships of the equations. This work seems to be the most interesting work in the literature seen in relation to the de- velopment of a generalised business analysis model.

 

Using the literature reviewed as a starting point with special impor-

tance being attached to the above authors, the structure and field of

applications of Eilon's model in lit. 30 will be analysed in detail.

 

After this analysis, a graphical analytical business model is developed in Chapter B including book keeping, accounting and financial concepts to be employed by the business management. Using this model it is possi-ble to carry out an actual managerial audit as described by Finn C. Sø- rensen, among others.

 

Chapter C defines an analytical mathematical business model based on the general graphical structure shown in Chapter B. As a special starting point is taken the fact that any sales curve may be composed of a piece- wise linear function. The basic element of the sales function is thus chosen as a linear function of time.

 

Based on the developed mathematical functions the most common accounting ratios are computed as a function of time.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- VIII -

 

Bela Gold's ratio technique is examined more ciosely, using general ma-thematical ratio functions developed in this report, and an attempt is made to explain it by means of these functions, which  are also used to illustrate the technical background of the computation of the rate of return in the Dupont pyramid.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

C H A P T E R  A

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 1 -

 

 

 

1.  An analytical business model

 

1.1.  Introduction

During the mentioned review of the litterature only one source was found, which was suitable for forming the basis of the development of

the general mathematical business model in Chapters B and C. This sour- ce was Samuel Eilon's article in OMEGA 1997, Vol. 5, No. 6: "A Profita- bility Model for Tactical Planning", lit. 30.

 

In the following the mentioned article will therefore be discussed as

an introduction to the analytical mathematical business model in Chap-

ter C.

 

1.1.1  S. Eilon's model

The article starts by pointing out that simple models reflecting aggre- gate company behaviour in response to changes imposed by management de- cisions and/or outside factors provide useful tools for management for tactical planning purposes.

 

As his starting point, Eilon takes the rate of return r expressed as:

 

     (p - c)V

 r =     ŸŸŸŸŸ                                                      (1)

        I

 

or

 

      

           earnings

r =   ŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸ                                            (2)

       total investment

 

where

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 2 -

 

 

p = unit price per unit of output

c = unit cost per unit of output

V = output units per time unit

I = total investment

 

Attention is drawn to the fact that for macro economic purposes it is

possible to compute the ratio r from the definition equation (2) and

thus obtain information on an industry's "profitability".

 

Equation (1) is a micro economic rewriting of (2) based on "logical"

considerations. The numerator in equation (1) is fairly well defined,

also in a micro economic model, but the denominator I, total assets,

which serves the main purpose, is difficult to determine in practice.

Additions to and disposals of assets as well as changes in the market

value of these assets take place currently.

 

The practical purpose of the computation of the rate of return is a

desire to obtain an equivalent measure of the return on investment. It

appears from the above that in practice the com putation of r involves

great uncertainty so that r is a relatively uncertain measure of profi- tability. If the following definitions are now introduced

 

 

       dp               dc               dI

p* =  ŸŸŸ  ;   c* =  ŸŸŸ  ;  I* =   ŸŸŸ  ,

       p                d                I

 

 

where the changes dp, dc, dV and dI are given, equation (1) can be

transformed into

 

 

          1        1 + V*

r* =  ŸŸŸŸŸŸ   (ŸŸŸŸŸ  (p* - (1 - a) c*) + V* - I*)             (3)

        1 + I*       a

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 3 -

 

 

                      p - c

given definition a = ŸŸŸŸŸ  = the relative profit margin.

                        p          

As regards equation (3), S. Eilon observes that it is an analytical tool for assessing the effects on r of changes of the variables of the

right hand side.

 

In practice, a functional inter relationship exists very often between

these variables; a later change in the selling price or the cost price will, for instance, bring about changes not only in investments (in

the working capital) but also in demand and hence output.

 

1.1.1.1.  Functional relationships and assumptions

Eilon assigns to the cost c per output unit the following conventional

functional expression:

 

         F      J

c = s + ŸŸ    +   ŸŸ                                                  (4) 

         V      V

 

where

 

 s    represents direct unit costs

 

 F

ŸŸ    represents indiret unit costs excl. interest

 V

 

   J

ŸŸ   represents interest charge per unit.

 V

 

Equation (4) is a so called traditional economic calculation of total

unit costs. It should, however, be noted that from a general accoun-

ting point of view there is no real justification for equation (4). It

is simply an appropriate formula for the unit cost function in relati-

on to the traditional theory of managerial economics, which makes it

possible to carry out simple partial operations research computations

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 4 -

 

 

concerning, for instance, profit maximization in relation to various

alter natives.

 

The stressing of the point that equation (4) has no real physical ju-

stification is due to the fact that equation (4) is a simple transfor- mation of equations (5) and (6).

 

TO = c V                                                           (5)

 

TO = s V + F + J                                                   (6)

 

Equation (5) is here a purely non physical definition equation (addi-

tion of simple "krone amounts") for the total costs TO specified via

the definition equation (6). It will be seen that these definition equa- tions give rise to problems in connection with the physical interpreta- tion. What is, for instance, meant by fixed costs, and how are they de- fned in relation to, say, the interest charges J ?

 

A transformation of equation (4) using the definitions s = f1 c , F/V

= f2 c and J/V = f3 c  gives

 

 

                1

c* = f1 s* + ŸŸŸŸŸ(f2 F* + f3 J* - (1 - f1) V*)                   (7)

              1 + V*

 

 

This equation (7) shows that with a good approximation we have:

 

c* = f1 s* + f2 F* + f3 J* - (1 - f1) V*                             (8)

 

Interpretation of the contents of, for example, (8) will show that the

percentage change of the unit costs is equal to the weighted sum of the percentage change of s, F, J and V.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 5 -

 

Concerning investments I, S. Eilon assumes:

 

IW = A + B                                                          (9)

 

I = IW + IF                                                        (10)

 

where

 

IW = the working capital

IF = investment in fixed assets

B  = bank loans + overdrafts

A  = other loans             

 

S. Eilon also defines:

 

w = IW/I                                                          (10a)

l = B/IW                                                          (10b)

J = j B , where j is the interest rate                            (lOc)

 

Equation (10) can now be transformed into:

 

I* = w I*W + (1 - w)I*F                                              (11)

 

Equation (9) can be transformed into:

 

I*W = (1 - l) A* + l B*                                              (12)

 

A combination of equation (12) and equation (11) will take the form:

 

I* =   w ((1 - l) A* + l B*) + (1 - w) I*F                            (13)

 

For use in the actual planning process of the business, S. Eilon assu-

mes that

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 6 -

 

 

I*F = 0                                                           (14)

 

and

 

A* = 0                                                            (15)

 

It is also assumed that w and l are constant (the artiticle does not

mention this explicitly).

 

Based on the mentioned assumptions equations (12) and (13) are then

reduced to

 

I*W = l B*                                                         (16)

 

and

 

I* = w l B*                                                        (17)

 

gives the conditions (14) and (15).

 

In connection with the determination of changes in the working capital

IW, S. Eilon writes:

 

"No single relationship between working capital and the 1evel of ac-

tivity in the firm is universally accepted and we may proceed to ex-

plore two possible assumptions."

 

These two assumptions are combined as a linear combination

 

I*W = g (p v)* + h(c V)*                                           (18)

 

which denotes that the working capital (tied up in the operating sy-

stem is changed as a linear combination of the change in sales and the

change in cost. S. Eilon claims that no controller has difficulty in

determining empirically the constants g and h. It must therefore be

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 7 -

 

possible to find a physical model which describes these empirical facts. A mathematical analytical solution to this problem is described

in Chapter C.

 

S. Eilon proceeds to consider three cases which are relevant for tac-

tical planning purposes:

 

1. Change of s, F and j

2. Change of V

3. Change of p

 

In the first case changes in the cost structure are considered. The

following two cases deal with changes in sales and changes in the mar-

ket price, i.e. two situations where the earnings structure is chan-

ged. However, as regards cases 2 and 3, it is natural to describe them

together as will be seen later. The things to be discussed are therefo- re as follows:

 

1. Change in the cost structure caused by changes in s, F and j.

 

2. Change in the earnings structure caused by changes in V given the

market elasticity e.

 

 

1.1.1.1.1.  Change in the cost structure

 

Attention is drawn to the fact that in his case 1 S. Eilon discusses

an iterative process, physical and mathematical, in connection with the final computation of c*. From a physical point of view, this is in full accordance with the accounting theory, as will be shown later in the ge- neral mathematical business model. S. Eilon attempts to provide this "fact" of the expressions de  scribed here through the mathematical convergence in the computation of total unit costs as shown in the article. In this respect, however, it does not seem to be a good idea to combine physical and mathematical facts too much since, as has already been

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

- 8 -

 

 

mentioned, S. Eilon employs a non physical definition of unit costs (see equation (4), which highly weakens the foundation of Eilon's conclusi- ons.

 

S. Eilon elaborates on this definiton of the unit cost, one of the prin- ciples of traditional theories of managerial economics, in case 1. It is exactly these conflicts between the physical conditions in the firm and the traditional theory of managerial economics which have caused the de- velopment of the mathematical business model described in Chapter C.

 

With a view to solving the existing mathematical problem, equation

(1Oc) is transformed into:

 

J* = j* + (1 + j*) B*                                               (2o)

 

The mathematical problem can now be solved by means of the followinq

previously shown equations (7), (16) and (18) together with the reated conditions:

 

Equations:

 

                1

c* = f1 s* +   ŸŸŸŸ (f2 F* + f3 J* - (1 - f1) V*)                    (21)

              1 + V*

 

J* = j* + (1 + j*) B*                                               (22)

 

I*W = l B*                                                          (23)

 

I*W =  g(p v)* + h(c v)*                                            (24)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 9 -

 

 

given the conditions

 

V* = 0                                                             (25)

 

p* = 0                                                             (26)

 

A solution is obtained as follows:

 

From equation (24) with the conditions (25) and (26) it follows that

 

I*W = h c*                                                          (27)

 

Equation (27) and (23) give

 

      h

B* = ŸŸ  c*                                                        (28)

      l

 

A combination of equation (28) and (22) gives

 

                   h

J* = j* + (1 + j*)  ŸŸ c*                                          (29)

                   l

 

A combination of equation (29) and (21) gives

 

       f1 s* + f2 F* + f3 j*

c* =  ŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸ                                      (30)

                     h

       1 - (1 + j*) ŸŸ f3

                     l

 

In equation (30) the question is raised whether

      

          h

(1 + j*) ŸŸ f3 < 1

          l

 

has been satisfied as, in practice, equation (lOb) shows that

 

 1     IW

ŸŸ = ŸŸ

 l      B

 

 

 

 

 

.

- l0 -

 

 

Normally will IW  < B, hence

 

 1    

ŸŸ < 1

 l      

 

As typically in practice h < 1, f3 < 0.5 and (1 + j*) < 1.5, inequa1ity

(31) gives

 

          h            1

(1 + j*) ŸŸ f3 < 1,2 ŸŸ 0.5

          l             1

 

or

 

          h

(1 + j*) ŸŸ f3 < 0.6

          l

 

From this will be seen that, in practice, inequality (31) has been sa-

tisfied.

 

S. Eilon introduces a new ratio H = IW /(c V) for the purpose showing

that inequality (31) has been satisfied in practice. This seems to be

a purely mathematical exercise without any relevant justification phy-

sically. It is once more pointed out that S. Eilon overinterprets the

mathematical consequences of the use of the equation (4) defined on the basis of managerial economics.

 

For the purpose of computing the rate of return the equations (3),

(lOa) and (18) are used to solve the equations:

 

         1       1 + V*

r* =  ŸŸŸŸŸ (ŸŸŸŸŸ(p* - (1 - a) c*) + V* - I*)                (32)

       1 + I*       a

 

      1

I =  ŸŸ IW                                                       (33)

      w

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

 - 11 -

 

 

I*W = g(p V)* + h(c v)*                                            (34)

 

with the conditions:

 

       f1 s* + f2 F* + f3 j*

c* =  ŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸ                                     (35)

                     h

       1 - (1 + j*) ŸŸ  f3

                     l

 

V* = 0                                                            (36)

p* = 0                                                            (37)

 

Equation (34) gives, cf. equation (27)

 

I*W = h c*                                                         (38)

 

Equation (33) is transformed into

 

I* = w I*W                                                         (39)

 

Equatioin (38) combined with equation (39) gives

 

I* = w h c*                                                       (40)

 

Equation (32) gives with equation (40) and the conditions (35),

(36) and (37) the following expression

 

            c*          1 - a

r* = - ŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸ  (ŸŸŸŸŸ  h w )                            (41)

        1 + w h c*        a

 

given

 

       f1 s* + f2 F* + f3 j*

c* =  ŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸ                                     (30)

                     h

       1 - (1 + j*) ŸŸ  f3

                     l

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 12 -

 

As regards equation (30) it should be noted that S. Eilon finds it

"justified" to define a quantity

     

c*0 = f1 s* + f2 F* + f3 j*                                          (42)

 

as unit costs, if h = 0, i.e. if no changes occur in the working ca-

pital with the given conditions V* = O and p* = 0 , cf. equa tion (38).

 

Equation (35) now takes the form

 

                c*0

c* =  ŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸ                                     (30)

                     h

       1 - (1 + j*) ŸŸ  f3

                     l

 

given

 

c*0 = f1 s* + f2 F* + f3 j*

 

Further, on the basis of the denominator in equation (43), S. Eilon

defines a ratio u as he seems to find it desirabie that all ratios oc-

cur in product form. For instance, as mentioned previously in this

connection, he also defines the ratio H = IW/(c V), which from the

point of view of accounting theory is a very specific concept.

 

A look at equation (43) will show that it takes the form of "ratios",

i.e. it contains dimensionless quantities, which are all ratios in the

firm. Therefore, it does not seem to be a very desirable measure to

introduce further ratios to give the equa tion a changed algebraic

structure.

 

However, for analytical purposes in connection with an analysis of the

numerical "behaviour" of equation (43) it may be useful to define a

parameter x given by

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 13 -

 

 

               h

x =  (1 + j*) ŸŸ  f3                                              (44)

               l

 

so that equation (43) is transformed into

 

         c*0

c* =  ŸŸŸŸŸ                                                    (45)

       1 - x

 

given

 

               h

x =  (1 + j*) ŸŸ  f3                                              (46)

               l

 

and

 

c*0 = f1 s* + f2 F* + f3 j*                                           (47)

 

Thus, by a preliminary nurnerical analysis of (45), x may be a11owed

to vary in the interval 0 < x < 1. It should be noted that x is here a

parameter. In the second phase of such an anal  ysis a numerical ana- lysis of equation (46) can be carried out, given certain selected va- lues of x.

 

 

1.1.2.1.2.  Change in the earnings structure

 

In this case where management wishes to consider the influence of the

market on the rate of return, etc., the following expression is assu-

med to apply

 

V* = - e p*                                                        (48)

 

given p*.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 14 -

 

The problem is thus given by the equations

 

                1

c* = f1 s* + ŸŸŸŸŸ (f2 F* + f3 J* - (1 - f1) V*)                  (49)

              1 + V*

 

J* = j* + (1 + j*) l B*                                            (50)

 

I*W = l B*                                                         (51)

 

I* = g(p V)* + h(c V)*                                             (52)

 

with the conditions:

 

s* = 0                                                            (53)

 

F* = 0                                                            (54)

 

j* = 0                                                            (55)

 

V* = - e p*                                                        (56)

 

Here equation (52) is transformed into

 

I*W = (g + h)V*  + (g p* + h c*)(1 + V*)                            (56a)

 

After the transformation of the above equations and  with the above

conditions the following equations are developed:

 

        1

c* = ŸŸŸŸŸ (f3 B* - (1 - f1) V*)                                (57)

      1 + V*

 

       1

B* =  ŸŸ((g + h) V* + (g p* + h c*)(1 + V*))                      (58)

       l

 

given the condition V* = - e p*                                    (59)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 15 -

 

Now equations (57), (58) and (59) give by simple reduction

 

                e p*                 1                   f3

c* = (1 - f1) ŸŸŸŸŸ  ŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸ  (1 - ŸŸŸŸŸŸŸ

              1 - e p*             f3               (1 - f1) l

                                   1 -  ŸŸŸ   h

                                 l

            

                        (h + g(1 + p* - e-1)))                     (60)

 

given the conditions

 

s* = 0                                                            (61)

 

F* = 0                                                            (62)

 

j* = 0                                                            (63)

 

V* = - e p*                                                        (64)

 

In connection with the practical use of equation (60) it might be de-

sirable to define a change in the unit cost cx* given by

 

                  e p*     

c*x = (1 - f1) ŸŸŸŸŸŸ                                          (65)

                1 - e p*

 

which has been obtained by putting s* = 0, F* = 0 and J* = 0 in equati- on (7). c*x can here be interpreted as the change in the unit cost if the only thing to be considered is a change in the price p.

 

Moreover, from equation (60) can be defined

 

      g

y = ŸŸŸ

      h

 

which may be interpreted as the need of investment in the working ca-

pital caused by sales in relation to caused by costs (see equation (18)).

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 16 -

 

The system of equations (60) .... (64) is now given the form

 

       c*x          x

c* = ŸŸŸŸ (1 - ŸŸŸŸ (1 + y(1 + p* - e-1)))                    (66)

     1 - x        1 - f1

 

given the conditions

 

               h

x =  (1 + j*) ŸŸ  f3                                              (67)

               l

 

      g

y = ŸŸŸ

      h

 

Using equations (3), (17), (57) and (60) .... (64) the following sy -

stem of equations can now be defined for the determination of the rate

of return.

 

Equation:

 

           1         1 - e p*

r* =  ŸŸŸŸŸŸŸ  (ŸŸŸŸŸŸ (p* - (1 - a) c*) - e p* - w I*W)     (69)

       1 + w I*W        a

 

given the conditions

 

s* = 0                                                            (70)

F* = 0                                                            (71)

j* = 0                                                            (72)

V* = - e p*                                                        (73)

 

I*W = (g + h)V*  + (g p* + h c*)(1 + V*)                             (74)

 

                e p*             1                   f3

c* = (1 - f1) ŸŸŸŸŸ  ŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸ  (1 - ŸŸŸŸŸŸŸ

              1 - e p*           f3              (1 - f1) l

                         1 -  ŸŸŸ h

                                 l

 

                        (h + g(1 + p* - e-1)))                      (75)

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 17 -

 

If changes are recorded only in V, the following system of equations

is obtained by replacing p* with V* and putting p* = 0 and e-1 = 0 in

the above equations:

 

                    V*             1                   f3

c* = - (1 - f1) ŸŸŸŸŸ  ŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸ  (1 - ŸŸŸŸŸŸŸ

                 1 - V*            f3              (1 - f1) l

                            1 -  ŸŸŸ h

                                   l

 

                                     (h + g))                     (76)

given the conditions

s* = 0                                                             (77)

F* = 0                                                             (78)

j* = 0                                                             (79)

e-1 = 0                                                             (80)

p* = 0                                                             (81)

 

and the system of equations:

 

           1               1 - a

r* =  ŸŸŸŸŸŸŸ   (V* - ŸŸŸŸŸ (1 + V*) c* + w I*W)               (82)

       1 + w I*W             a

 

given the conditions

s* = 0                                                             (83)

F* = 0                                                             (84)

j* = 0                                                             (85)

 

I*W = (g + h(1 + c*)) V* + h c*                                      (86)

 

                    V*             1                   f3

c* = - (1 - f1) ŸŸŸŸŸ  ŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸ  (1 - ŸŸŸŸŸŸŸ

                 1 - V*            f3              (1 - f1) l

                           1 -  ŸŸŸ h

                                   l

 

                                     (h + g))                     (87)

 

Attention is called to the fact that the resuits in this Chapter dif-

fer from S. Eilon's results in cases 2 and 3. The following Chapter

will indude a general discussion of S. Eilon's results and models in

the light of the results achieved here.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 - 18 -

 

1.1.2. Assesment of S. Eilon's model

 

It has already been pointed out that the basis of S. Eilon's model gi- ves rise to the question as to whether it serves any purpose to carry out these computations and at the same time attach such fundamental importance to the models shown in the article in relation to the phy- sical business situation.

 

Thus, S. Eilon assumes that eguation (4) is fundamental, i.e. a funda- mental starting point for considerations based on managerial economies. With reference to eguations (5) and (6) it was stated that this is a point of view which should be examined more closely. This examination leads to the point that eguation (4) is a purely mathematical definition equation, i.e. an equation which is not founded on real physical facts (equation (6)'s right hand side consists of a sum of elements of widely differing physical origin with only one thing in

common: the value "DKK").

 

Owing to the mathematical structure of equation (4) it will mathema-

                                    d      J(V)

tically be convergent as where U £ ŸŸŸ  (ŸŸŸ) £ K , in practice U

                                    dV      V

and K are constants. The physical convergence also exists in connec- tion with the changes in the tactical planning process (transients) under consideration. It should be noted that the mathematical model shows the relationships between changes in states" (i.e. time is not included explicitly) with the related mathematical characteristics of the manner of converging. The physical activity/cash flow model of the business is knovn also in practice to possess convergent characteri- stics as a function of time. See chapter C.

 

Against this background it is important not to attach too great impor-

tance here to the applicability of S. Eilon's model to an interpreta-

tion of the dynamics of the firm (for tactical planning purposes).

Thus, the mathematical business model, Chapter C, is not to take state

functions as its starting point but only use a time description of the

functions.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

 - 19 -

 

The graphical description used by S. Eilon can only be regarded as a

dear description of the equations between the individual variable.

being studied.

 

In Chapter B a physical model description of the business will the-

refore be given first, the greatest importance being attached to ma-

king the physical/financial description as realistic as possible. Af-

ter this the mathematical déscription is developed in Chapter C.

 

The results achieved in the present Chapter A differ from S. Eilon's

results as far as computations of the effects of changes in the ear-

nings structure are concerned. It is pointed out that S. Eilon's un-

structuralized consideration of the mathematical methods of solution

may be the reason for the deviating results in the article.

 

The central equation (18), which estimates the relationship between the working capital tied up in the operating system, will be analysed in detail in Chapter C.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

C H A P T E R  B

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 20 -

 

2.  An analytical graphical business model

 

This Chapter describes an analytical graphical business model (see Fig. 2.1.). This model will form the basis of a mathematical analytical description of the business so that this description can be used by the business management for their principal planning activities. The model will integrate principal elements of managerial economics and the ac- counting theory, it being assumed that the business comprises an acti- vity/cash flow and related principal assets (accounts payable, accounts receivable, inventories). It is management's task to achieve the best possible composition of this general structure by using some of the ra- tios defined in the model.

 

2.1.  Activity parameters

 

2.1.1.  Sales

The volume of goods sold by the firm per unit is denoted with S'u. Sales are here divided into two main components of which one is the reference sales S'u,kon, which refers to the share of sales which is paid for in cash. The other component of sales is denoted with S'u,deb,which refers to the share of sales which is paid for by the trade accounts receivable the debit time deltaD after delivery from the firm. Here the following eguation applies:

 

S'u(t) = S'u,deb(t) + S'u,kon(t)                                         (88)

 

2.1.2.  Purchases

The firm is supplied with a number of labor hours per time unit a'i.

 

The firm is supplied with the volume of goods per time unit V'i. This flow of goods consists of two main components of which one is the refe- rence purchase V'i,kon, and the other the goods purchased on credit V'i,kre, which are paid for by the firm after the credit time dK.

 

 

 

- 21 -

 

 

 

Figure 2.1

 

(Click on the figure for 200%)

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 22 -

 

The following equation applies:

 

V'i(t) = V'i,kre(t) + V'i,kon(t)                                        (89)

 

The firm is supplied with the fixed volume of resources per time unit F'i. This flow of resources may, for example, include electricity, administration, heating, rent, etc.

 

2.1.3.  Inventories

The volume of raw materials per time unit Q'i is added to the raw mate-

rials inventory consisting of the volume RL. From the raw materials in- ventory is deduced the raw materials volume Q'u. The following equation

applies here:

 

       t

RL =   ò (Q'i(t) - Q'u(t))dt                                       (90)

      0

The volume of finished goods per time unit Z'i is added to the finished

goods inventory consisting of the volume FL. From the finished goods

inventory is deduced the finished goods volume Z'u. The following equa- tion applies here:

 

       t

FL =   ò(Z'i(t) - Z'u(t))dt                                        (91)

      0

 

2.2.  Payment parameters, operations

 

2.2.1.  Sales

The total volume of means of payment per time unit from the customers is denoted with S'i. This payments flow consists of two components. One component is the payments flow S'i,kon stemming from the cash sales flow 

S'u,kon. The other component S'i,deb is the payments flow stemming from the credit sales flow S'u,deb. Here the following equation applies:

 

S'i(t) = S'i,kon(t) + S'i,deb(t)                                        (92)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 23 -

 

2.2.2.  Purchases

The total volume of means of payment per time unit for operations is denoted with U'b. This payments flow is composed of three components, a'b and V'b and F'b. a'b is the payments flow corresponding to the flow of hours consumed a'i, V'b is the payments flow corresponding to the flow of raw material purchases V'i, F'b is the payments flow corresponding to the flow of fixed resources consumed F'i. The following equation applies:

 

U'b(t) = a'b(t) + V'b(t) + F'b(t)                                   (93)

 

The payments flow V'b is made up of two components. One component is the payments flow V'b,kon corresponding to the cash purchases of rawmaterials V'i,kon; the other component is the payments flow V'b,kre corresponding to the credit purchase of raw materials V'i,kre. The following equation applies:

 

V'b(t) = V'b,kon(t) + V'b,kre(t)                                       (94)

 

2.3.  Market parameters, sales

With a viev to depicting the fundamental financial effects of the mar- ket on the firm as well as its effects on earnings the market is cha- racterized by three basic components q , p and dD. They also describe the fundamental link between the firm's sales of goods and the related payments flows.

 

2.3.1.  Cash sales ratio q

The cash sales ratio is defined by the equation;

 

S'u,kon(t) =   q S'u(t)                                             (95)

where 0 £ q  £  1

 

In a manufacturing business q will typically be placed in the in- terval 0 £ q  £  0.2. In a supermarket q  will typically be in the interval 0.8 £ q  £  1.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 24 -

 

2.3.2.  The price p

The price of the firm's product(s) is defined by the eguations

 

S'u,kon,1(t) = p S'u,kon(t)                                             (96)

 

S'i,kon(t) = S'u,kon,1(t)                                               (97)

 

where S'u,kon,1(t) is the flow of debts corresponding to the sales flow S'u,kon(t) (i.e. the current sending out of invoices stating the amount of debt; see equation (96)). Equation (97) expresses the fact that the flow of debts S'u,kon,1(t) is equal to the payments flow from the customers (cash payment).

 

In practice, it should be noted that there is normally only a tempora- ry time lag between invoicing and sales. However, it has a temporary negative effect on liquidity and the computation of results. Manage- ment will therefore as far as possible make sure that invoicing is done without the mentioned delays.

 

2.3.3.  Debit time dD

This model defines the debit time dD as the time from the time of de- livery of the goods from the firm until the time of payment by the cu- stomer for the goods. In practice, dD is spread over the individual cu- stomers but with well defined terms of payment the mean value can be adopted.

 

The definition of dD can be expressed by the equations

 

 

S'u,deb,1(t) = p S'u,deb(t)                                            (98)

 

V'deb,dD(t) = S'u,deb,1(t - dD)                                          (99)

 

S'i,deb(t) = V'deb,dD(t)                                              (100)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 25 -

 

S'u,deb,1 refers here to the invoice flow corresponding to the credit sales flow S'u,deb cf. equation (98). Equation (99) gives a funational description of a function V'deb,dD(t), which can be defined as the pay- ments flow (documents) corresponding to the actual receipt of payments S'i,deb(t) cf. equation (100). In practice, no time lag is found between the two last mentioned functions.

 

In pratice, attention should be paid to the fact that there may be a time lag in the business between invoicing and sales, the result being changes in liquidity and the computation of earnings. Management usu- ally aims at applying equation (98) in practice, i.e. no time lag.

 

2.4.   Market parameters, purchases

With a view to depicting the fundamental financial effects of the pur- chasing market on the firm as well as its effects on costs, it is cha- racterized by four basic components epsilon, q1, q2 and dK. They describe the fundamental link between the firm's purchases of resources and the related payments flows.

 

2.4.1.  Cash purchases ratio e

The cash purchases ratio is defined by the equation:

 

V'i,kon(t) = e V'i(t)                                                (101)

where 0 £ e  £  1

 

In, say, a manufacturing business e will typically be placed in the interval 0 £ e  £  0.2. This is also a typical feature in a trading firm.

 

 

2.4.2.  The price q1 of raw materials

The price of the firms raw materials is defined by the equation:

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 26 -

 

 

V'i,kon,1(t) = q1 V'i,kon(t)                                            (102)

 

V'b,kon(t) = V'i,kon,1(t)                                              (103)

 

where V'i,kon,1(t) is the flow of debts corresponding to the raw materials flow V'i,kon(t) (i.e. the current receipt of invoices stating the amounts of debts); see equation (102). Equation (103) expresses the fact that the flow of debts V'i,kon,1(t) is equal to the payments flow to suppliers (cash payment).

 

In practice, attention should bepaid to the fact that the time lag between the supplier's invoicing and the supplies of raw materials is usually a temporary feature which has a temporary positive affect on liquidity and the computation of results.

 

2.4.3.  The price q2 of labor hours

The price of the firm's labor hours is defined by the equations

 

a'i,1(t) = q2 a'i(t)                                               (104)

 

a'b(t) = a'i,1(t)                                                  (105)

 

where a'i,1(t) is the time ticket flow corresponding to the flow of labor hours used a'i(t) (i.e. the current issuing of time tickets stating wages earned); see equation (17). Equation (18) expresses the fact that the time ticket flow a'i,1(t) is equal to the time rate flow a'b(t).

 

In practice there is a certain time lag between functions on the right hand side and the left hand side of the equal sign in equation (104). This time lag is ignored here. There is usually no time lag between

the functions of equation (105), or the time lag is relatively small and of no importance here.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 27 -

 

2.4.4.  Credit time dK

This model defines the credit time dK as the time from the time of de- livery of the raw materials to the firm until the time of payment by the firm for the raw materials. In practice, dK is spread over the in- dividual suppliers but with well defined terms of payment the mean va- lue can be used. The definition of dK can be expressed by the equati- ons:

 

V'i,kre,1(t) = q1 V'i,kre(t)                                           (106)

 

V'kre,dK(t) = V'i,kre,1(t - dK)                                         (107)

 

V'b,kre(t) = V'kre,dK(t)                                              (108)

 

where V'i,kre,1(t) refers here to the invoice flow corresponding to the

credit purchases flow V'i,kre(t), cf. equation (106). Equation (107) gi-ves a functional description of a function V'kre,dK(t) which can be defined as the payment order flow (documents) corresponding to the actual effecting of payments V'b,kre(t), cf. equation (108). In practice, there is no time lag between the two last mentioned functions.

 

In practice, attention should be paid to the fact that the time lag between the supplier's invoicing and the supplies of raw materials is usually a temporary feature which has a temporary positive affect on liquidity and the computation of results.

 

The following equations are defined in relation to the fixed resources consumed F'i and the related fixed costs F'b.

 

F'i,1(t) = k F'i(t)                                                (109)

 

F'b(t) = F'i,1(t)                                                  (110)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 28 -

 

where F'i,1(t) in equation (109) refers to the flow of debts in the form of invoices (stating amounts) corresponding to the fixed resoures flow F'i(t). k denotes a symbolic operator in the form of an average price of the fixed resources unit. In practice, there is some time lag between the functions in eguation (110). As, however, the fixed costs by definition are constant in time, such a time lag is not important in this context.

 

3.1  Income statement

In this Chapter an income statement for operations is presented (be- fore depreciation, etc.) using the general main principles of accoun- ting theory.

 

3.1.1     Sales of goods

Sales of goods are defined on the basis of the following equations:

 

S'u,kon,2(t) = S'u,kon,1(t)                                             (111)

 

S'u,deb,2(t) = S'u,deb,1(t)                                             (112)

 

S'u,1(t) = S'u,kon,2(t) + S'u,deb,2(t)                                   (113)

 

Eguation (111) expresses the fact that the flow of debts (in the form of invoices with statement of amounts) S'u,kon,1(t) gives rise to an e- qually large information flow S'u,kon,2(t). This quantity is identital with the current crediting to the cash sales account.

 

From equation (112) follows that the flow of debts S'u,deb,1(t) causes an equally large information flow S'u,deb,2(t). This quantity is iden- tical to the current crediting to the credit sales account.

 

Total uales in the form of the information flow S'u,1(t) corresponding to the total crediting to the sales account are then obtained from e- quation (113).

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

 

 

- 29 -

 

3.1.2  Costs

The costs of the firm in connection with production and sales are de- fined by the following equations:

 

V'i,kon,2(t) = V'i,kon,1(t)                                            (114)

 

V'i,kre,2(t) = V'i,kre,1(t)                                            (115)

 

a'i,2(t) = a'i,1(t)                                                (116)

 

F'i,2(t) = F'i,1(t)                                                (117)

 

U'd(t) = V'i,kon,2(t) + V'i,kre,2(t) + a'i,2(t) + F'i,2(t)                  (118)

 

Equation (114) expresses the fact that the invoice flow from the cash purchase V'i,kon,1(t) is corrently debited to the cash purchases account

to the extent of the cash flow V'i,kon,2(t).

 

Equation (115) expresses the fact that the invoice flow from the cre- dit purchase V'i,kon,1(t) is currently debited to credit purchases account to the extent of the cash flow V'i,kre,2(t).

 

Equation (116) denotes the functional relationship between the time ticket flow a'i,1(t) and the current debiting to the time rate account of the wage payment flow a'i,2(t).

 

Equation (117) expresses the functional relationship between the in- voice flow F'i,1(t) for fixed costs and the current debiting of the cash flow F'i,2(t) to the fixed costs account.

 

The total cost flow is defined by equation (118).

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 30 -

 

3.1.2.1  Inventories, additions (with signs)

By way of introduction, it is mentioned that the signs relating to additions to inventories (as a mean time value) are assumed to be the same as those relating to additions to sales (as a mean time value). Against this background the additions to the individual inventories will for principal planning purposes have the same signs. The inventories only serve as "standby stores" in case of emergancy events" i.e. in normal operation state "the materials and products go directly through the factory. Thus, the following systems of equations apply:

 

                           Q'i(t) > 0

                           Q'u(t) = 0

d S'u

ŸŸŸŸ  > 0      Þ                                                     (119)

dt

                           Z'i(t) > 0

                           Z'u(t) = 0

 

 

                           Q'i(t) = 0

                           Q'u(t) = 0

d S'u

ŸŸŸŸ  = 0      Þ                                                     (120)

dt

                           Z'i(t) = 0

                           Z'u(t) = 0

 

 

                           Q'i(t) = 0

                           Q'u(t) > 0

d S'u

ŸŸŸŸ        < 0      Þ                                                    (121)

dt

                           Z'i(t) = 0

                           Z'u(t) > 0

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 31 -

 

The system of equations (119) denotes that inventories rise when sales rise.

 

The system of equations (120) denotes that inventories are constant when sales remain unchanqed.

 

The system of equations (121) denotes that inventories fall when sales fall.

 

Based on these main principles for the model the following equations can be developed.

 

Q'i,1(t) = qR Q'i(t)                                               (122)

 

Q'u,1(t) = qR Q'u(t)                                               (123)

 

Z'i,1(t) = qF Q'i(t)                                               (124)

 

Z'u,1(t) = qF Z'u(t)                                               (125)

 

U'tl(t) = Q'i,1(t) + Z'i,l(t)                                        (126)

 

U'al(t) = Q'u,1(t) + Z'u,1(t)                                        (127)

 

where    Q'i,1(t)   is the flow of additions to raw materials invento-

                    ries corresponding to the additions to rawmateri-

                    als inventory records with statement of amounts.

 

         Q'u,1(t)   is the flow of deductions to raw materials invento-

                    ries corresponding to the deductions to raw mate-

                    rials inventory records with statement of amounts.

 

         Z'i,1(t)   is the flow of additions to finished goods invento-

                    ries corresponding to the additions to finished

                    goods inventory records with statement of amounts.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 32 -

 

         Z'u,1(t)   is the flow of deductions to finished goods inven-

                    inventories corresponding to the deductions to fi-

                    nished goods inventory records with statement of

                    amounts.

 

          qR         denotes the caiculated rav material price per unit 

                    of finished goods.

 

          qF         denotes the caiculated direct cost price per unit 

                    of finished goods.

 

          U'tl(t)   is total additions to inventories.

 

          U'al(t)   is total deductions from inventories.

 

The system of equations (119), (120) and (121) can nov be given the form:

 

d S'u

ŸŸŸŸ  > 0      Þ       U'tl(t) > 0  and  U'al(t) = 0            (128)

d t

 

d S'u

ŸŸŸŸ  = 0      Þ       U'tl(t) = 0  and  U'al(t) = 0            (129)

d t

 

d S'u

ŸŸŸŸ  < 0      Þ       U'tl(t) = 0  and  U'al(t) > 0            (130)

d t

Attention is dravn to the fact that the physical model based on the FIFO principle can be deseribed mathematically only by

 

        d S'u

sign ( ŸŸŸŸ ) = sign (U'tl(t))                                 (131)

        d t

 

given U'al(t) = 0                                                 (132)

 

and U'tl(t) is computed with signs.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 33 -

 

3.1.3.  Resourceconsumption (incl. F'i,1)

Resources consumed U'd,1,1(t) can be defined by the following equations:

 

 d S'u

ŸŸŸŸ  > 0      Þ        U'd,1,1(t) = U'd(t) - U'tl(t)             (133)

 d t                       given U'al(t) = 0

 

 d S'u

ŸŸŸŸ  = 0      Þ        U'd,1,1(t) = U'd(t)                      (134)

 d t

 

 d S'u

ŸŸŸŸ  < 0      Þ        U'd,1,1(t) = U'd(t) - U'al(t)             (135)

 d t                       given U'tl(t) = 0

 

3.1.4.  Operation profit (before interest and depreciation)

The operating profit (before interest and depreciation etc.) is defi- ned by the equation:

 

O'(t) = S'u,1(t) - U'd,1,1(t)                                        (136)

 

3.1.5  Operating profit incl. inventory depreciation

If a tax year of the length T is considered in a period of time

t1 £ t £ t1 + T where t1 is a time selected at random, the following

functions can be defined:

 

       t1+T

Vkøb =   ò  q1 V'i(t) dt                                           (137)

       t1

w = w(t1)                                                         (138)

an = an(t)                                                        (139)

 

In equation (137) Vkøb represents the purchases of goods in the period t1 £ t £ t1 + T.

 

Equation (138) defines w(t1) as the total inventory value at time t1. an(t) in the equation defines the inventory depreciation rate.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 34 -

 

Materials consumed computed for tax purposes is then derived from the following equation (140):

 

Vskat = Vkøb + w(t1) - (w(t1)/(1 - an(t1))

 

         t1+T

               + ò (U'tl(t) - U'al(t)) dt) (1 - an(t1 - T))                 (140)

         t1

 

For principal planning purposes the mean time value of an(t) for a given business will be a constant an and limited i.e.

0 < an < 0.3 . Based on this assumption equation (140) gives

 

                    t1+T

Vskat = Vkøb - (1 - an) ò (U'tl(t) - U'al(t)) dt                       (141)

                    t1

Materials consumed for operations is defined by the following equation

(54a):

                             t1+T

Vdrift = Vkøb + w(t1) - (w(t1) +  ò (U'tl(t) - U'al(t)) dt)            (141a)

                             t1

or

            t1+T

Vdrift = Vkøb -  ò (U'tl(t) - U'al(t)) dt)                             (142)

             t1

If equation (142) and equation (141) are combined, the following equations are developed:

 

                t1+T

Vskat = Vdrift + an ò (U'tl(t) - U'al(t)) dt                            (143)

               t1

 

              t1+T

Vskat = Vdrift +  ò an(U'tl(t) - U'al(t)) dt                            (144)

              t1

 

 

 

 

.

- 35 -

 

On the basis of equation (144) the following functions can be defined:

 

U'tl,1(t) = U'tl(t)                                                (145)

 

U'al,1(t) = U'al(t)                                                (146)

 

In equation (145) U'tl,1(t) denotes total additions to inventories from a taxation point of view. U'al,1(t) denotes in equation (146) total de-ductions from inventories from a taxation point of view.

 

With the following definition equation:

 

B'ln(t) = an (U'tl,1(t) - U'al,1(t))                                  (147)

 

equation (144) can be transformed into

 

              t1+T

Vskat = Vdrift +  ò B'ln(t) dt                                       (148)

              t1

On the basis of equation (148) the following equation (149) can be defined:

 

O'DS = O' - B'ln                                                   (149)

 

where O'DS is the operating profit adjusted for inventory depreciation.

 

4.1.    Change in liquidity (operations)

The cash flow released by operations, the change in liquidity, is de- fined by the following equation (150):

 

l'(t) = S'i(t) - U'b(t)                                           (150)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 36 -

 

5.1.   Cash balance

The cash balance of the firm is designated by M, which, in relation to the present principal planning model, is very small in practice, i.e. M(t) = 0. The following equation can now be developed:

 

i'e = l' + i'K - y'B - y'L - H'S,1                                     (152)

 

where

 

i'e      is the self financing flow

 

y'B      is the service of bank loans

 

y'L      is the service of other loans

 

i'K      is current raise of loans for operations

 

H'S,1    is tax payments

 

5.2.   Bank loans

The firm is financed currently by trading credits in the form of the cash flow i'B. The equation is defined as follows:

 

i'B,1(t) = i'B(t)                                                  (152)

 

where i'B,1(t) is the information flow in the form of loan documents with statement of amounts corresponding to the cash flov i'B(t). The bank charges currently interest r'B(t) on the amount outstanding

B = B(t) where r'B(t) is the document flow with statement of interest. The following equation appliess:

 

n'B(t) = i'B,1 + r'B                                               (153)

 

where n'B(t) is the firm's current crediting to the bank account.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 37 -

 

The current service payments y'B(t) to the bank give rise to a payment order flow with statement of amounts y'B,1(t). We have:

 

y'B,1(t) = y'B(t)                                                  (154)

 

The payRent order flov y'B,1(t) involves a corresponding current debi- ting to the bank account in the form of y'B,2(t). The following equati- on therefore applies:

 

y'B,2(t) = y'B,1(t)                                                 (155)

 

5.3.  Loans (long term)

The long term financing of the business is represented by the cash flow i'L. The following equation applies:

 

i'L,1(t) = i'L(t)                                                  (156)

 

where i'L,1(t) is the information flow in the form of loan documents with statement of amounts corresponding to the cash flow i'L(t). On the loan L current interest r'L(t) is charged where r'L(t) is the document flow with statement of interest. The following equation applies:

 

n'L(t) = i'L,1(t) + r'L(t)                                          (157)

 

where n'L(t) is the firm's total current crediting to the loan account.

 

The following equation applies:

 

i'L(t) = i'L,1(t) + i'D(t)                                          (158)

 

where i'L,D(t) denotes the long term financing flow to the working ca- pital, and i'L,1(t) is the long term financing flow to the fixed capi- tal.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 38 -

 

The following equation applies:

 

i'K(t) = i'B(t) + i'L,D(t)                                         (159)

 

The current service payments y'L(t) to lender give rise to a payment order flow with statement of amounts y'L,1(t). We have

 

y'L,1(t) = y'B(t)                                                  (160)

 

The payment order flow y'L,1(t) involves a corresponding current debi-ting to the loan account in the form of y'L,2(t). The following equati- on therefore applies:

 

y'L,2(t) = y'L,1(t)                                                 (161)

 

6.1.  Investment (in fixed capital)

The firm's current investment in fixed capital is denoted i'(t). The following equation applies:

 

i'(t) = i'L,1(t) + i'e(t)                                           (162)

 

It is pointed out that, in practice, i'L,D(t) currently converts short term liabilities into long term liabilities, which means that at a strategic level alone i'L,D = 0. As to i'e(t), there is no unique defi- nition of i'e(t) as it depends on the financing and market situation. Roughly speaking, i'e(t) is the average cash flow which can be with- drawn from the business without changing the existing product, invest- nent and financing structure and the necessary financial reserves set aside for an appropriate future development of the businees.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 39 -

 

7.1.   Depreciation (for tax purposes)

It is normal to distinguish between depreciation for tax purposes and depreciation for accounting purposes. Depreciation for accounting pur- poses is used with the object of comparing alternative projects on the basis of special cost principles, which, for example, are mentioned in connection with equation (4). These principles are pure- ly OR mathe- matical models and do not reflect the physical business situation.

 

Here we shall only take an overall view of the financial flow of the firm for which reason depreciation for tax purposes will be used. Such depreciation will only reflect the actual effects on liquidity (after tax).

 

The following equations apply:

 

i'1(t) = i'(t)                                                    (163)

 

          t

D(t) =   ò  (i'1(t) - d'1(t))dt                                   (164)

         0

 

where i'1(t) represents the current debiting to the tax depreciation account corresponding to the investment flow i'(t). d'1(t) is the cur- rent crediting to the same account (i.e. current "depreciation").

 

D(t) represents the balance of the tax depreciation account. The de- preciation charges d'(t) are calculated on the basis of this account, and the following expressions apply:

 

d'1(t) = d'(t)                                                   (163a)

d'2(t) = d'(t)                                                   (164a)

 

where d'2(t) is the depreciation flow which is inciuded in the basis of computation of the taxable income.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 40 -

 

8.1.  Interest (for tax puroses)

Interest is usually computed for two main purposes. One concerns the income statement for tax purposes, the other concerns internal compu- tation purposes such as the effect of interest on the income statement as a whole or in connection with special computations.

 

No distinction will be made here between the two purposes. The inter- est charges will be placed in this model with the sole aim of depic- ting the fundamental financial characteristics.

 

The following equations are defined:

 

r'B,1(t) = r'B(t)                                                  (165)

 

r'L,1(t) = r'L(t)                                                  (166)

 

r'BL(t) = r'B,1(t) + r'L,1(t)                                        (167)

 

where r'B,1(t) denotes the current recording of interest payment to the

bank. r'L,1(t) denotes the current recording of interest payments to other lenders. The recording of total interest payments is designated r'BL(t).

 

9.1.  Tax payments

According to the principles governing computation of the taxable income the following equations apply:

 

f'u(t) = d'2(t) + r'BL(t)                                          (168)

 

H'S(t) = s (O'DS(t) - f'u(t))                                      (169)

 

H'S,1(t) = H'S(t)                                                 (169a)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 41 -

 

where f'u(t) is a state function for the computation of tax, cf. equa- tion (168), s is the tax rate, H'S(t) is the computed tax payment and H'S,1(t) is the tax payment flow.

 

 

10.1.  Principal ratios

As appears from Fig. 2.1, the following principal ratios in the firm are important to the understanding of the dynamic (tactical) characte- ristics of the firm.

 

      Operating profit                           O'(t)

 

      Change in liquidity                        l'(t)

 

      Working capital (net)                      K'(t)

 

      Contribution ratio                         DG(t)

 

      Depreciation                               d'2(t)

 

      Interest                                   r'BL(t)

 

These ratios will be discussed in detail in the following.

 

10.1.1.  Operating profit O'(t)

Using different assumptions concerning prices and changes in principal assets (accounts payable, accounts receivable, inventories) it is pos- sible via Fig. 2.1 to assess the effects on the operating profit. A reduction of the raw materials inventories in a situation with raw ma- terials prices which are higher than the prices of the raw materials inventories but othervise constant will increase the profit temporari- ly in the period concerned.

 

One of the things that will be seen is that the profit O'(t) is inde- pendent of the volume of trade accounts payable and the volume of tra- de accounts receivable.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

- 42 -

 

10.1.2.  Change in liquidity l'(t)

Other things being equal, the following expression, cf. Fig. 2.1., ap- plies:

 

d S'u

ŸŸŸŸ  > 0      Þ     l'(t) < O'(t)                            (170)

d t

 

Equation (170) shows that the profit O'(t) is larger than the change in

liquidity in the case of growing sales in the firm, the reason being the funds tied up, calculated with signs, in principal assets (ac-

counts receivable and inventories),

 

d S'u

ŸŸŸŸ  = 0      Þ     l'(t) = O'(t)                            (171)

d t

 

Equation (171) shows that the change in liquidity is equal to the pro-fit in the case of constant sales, the reason being an unchanged volu- me of principal assets (accounts payable, accounts receivable and in- ventories).

 

d S'u

ŸŸŸŸ  < 0      Þ     l'(t) > O'(t)                            (172)

d t

 

From equation (172) appears that in the case of falling sales the change in liquidity becomes greater than the operating profit owing to a reduced volume of principal assets (accounts payable, accounts receivable and inventories).

 

The above shows how important it is for the business to keep the cash budget currently up to date as the profit and the financial circum- stances of the business may differ substantially from each other. It should be noted that if the net principal assets are negative, the inequality signs in (170) and (172) must be reversed.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 43 -

 

10.1.3.  Working capital K(t).

If the working capital is denoted K(t), the definition eguation for net capital tied up in the operating system will apply:

 

K(t) = Vdeb(t) + FL(t) + RL(t) - Vkre(t)                            (173)

 

The following definition equation will also apply:

 

d K(t)

ŸŸŸŸ  + l'(t) = O'(t)                                          (174)

d t

 

Equation (174) shows that the profit is equal to the change in liqui- dity + the increment of the net working capital tied up.

 

If equation (174) is transformed, the following equation is derived:

 

d K(t)

ŸŸŸŸ  = O'(t) - l'(t)                                          (175)

d t

 

Equation (175) denotes that the difference between the operating pro- fit and the change in liquidity is equal to the financing requirements for operations in the period under review.

 

10.1.4.  Contribution ratio DG(t)

The contribution ratio is defined by equation (176):

 

DG(t) = (O'(t) + F'b(t))/S'u,1(t)                                  (176)

 

Equation (176) shows that DG is independent of the amount of sales and defines the share of sales which will cover fixed costs, etc. The point is stressed here that a high contribution ratio does not imply that there is "money" to cover the fixed costs. For further details see section 10.1.2. as the size of l'(t) gives only an indication of the ability of the firm to pay fixed costs, etc.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 44 -

 

10.1.5.  Depreciation

Depreciation contributes to influencing the firm's liquidity, cf. e- quation (169). Assuming that the investments are made as individual projects at time intervals, it is shown that depreciation in the peri- ods between investments causes liquidity to rise owing to the reducti- on in tax payments.

 

However, it should be noted that of the cash flow released after tax there must be funds to cover repayment commitments in connection with loans raised. The effect of the cash flow released after tax described above is therefore partial and must be seen in relation to the repay- ment commitments.

 

In chapter C will be shown that for practical reasons the division described here is desirable for the understanding of the financial components of the cash flow released.

 

10.1.6.  Interest r'BL

From Fig. 2.1 and from equations (168) and (169) is apparent that in- terest payments reduce the cash flow released after tax. Thus, the net effect on cash flow released (to be defined in charter C) stems partly from the computation of income for tax purposes, partly from the pay- ment of interest on total loans.

 

The computation of interest on total loans seen in relation to a given level of activity will be defined later.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

C H A P T E R  C

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 45 -

 

 

11.  An analytical mathematical business model

This Chapter presents a new analytical mathematical model description of the business. This model has been developed for use in the tactical planning process. No reference can be made to a similar model in exist- ing literature. The theoretical literature which gets nearest is S. Eilon's article discussed in Chapter A in the thesis.

 

11.1.  Physical and financial functions in the operating system

In the following further definitions of mathematical functions and their relationships will be established. The sole justification of these defi- nitions is that they provide the basis of a clear and generally coherent system of equations between ratios.

 

11.1.1.  Sales

A basic sales volume is defined:

 

S'u0 = S'u(0)                                                     (177)

 

where S'u0 is the volume of sales S'u at time t = 0, i.e. at the beginning of the simulation period.

 

The development of sales during the time period is defined by equation (91):

 

d S'u(t)

ŸŸŸŸ    = as S'u0                                                 (178)

d t

 

where as is constant.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 46 -

 

The following equation now applies:

 

S'u(t) = S'u0(1 + as t)                                            (179)

where t ³ 0

 

11.1.2.  Inventories.

Let a ratio hF be defined so that equation (180) applies:

 

hF = FL(t)/S'u(t)                                                 (180)

 

for t  ³ 0, hF being a positive constant which is designated "finished goods inventory time". Another ratio hR is defined so that equation (181) applies:

 

hR = RL(t)/S'u(t)                                                 (181)

 

for t  ³ 0  being a positive constant which is designated "raw materi- als inventory time".

 

From equation (180) follows:

 

FL(t) = hF S'u(t)                                                 (182)

 

The definition equation applies:

 

                 t

FL(t) = FF(0) +  ò  Z'i(t) dt                                     (183)

                0

 

which substituted into equation (182) gives:

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

 - 47 -

 

         t

FL(0) +  ò Z'i(t) dt = hF S'u(t)                                   (184)

        0

or

 

 t

 ò Z'i(t) dt = hF S'u(t) - FL(0)                                   (185)

 0

If equation (179) is used in equation (185), the following expression is derived:

 

 t

 ò Z'i(t) dt = hF S'u0 as t + (hF S'u0 - FL(0))                       (186)

 0

For t = 0 equation (180) gives the following expression:

 

hF = FL(0)/S'u(0)                                                 (187)

 

Using equation (187) together with equation (186) we have:

 

 t

 ò  Z'i(t) dt = hF S'u0 as t                                       (188)

 0

The solution to the integral equation (188) is:

 

Z'i(t) = hF S'u0 as                                                (189)

 

The flow of goods Z'i(t) to the finished goods inventory may then be defined by equations (190) and (191):

 

Z'i(t) = hF S'u0 as                                                (190)

for as ³ 0

 

and

 

Z'u(t) = - hF S'u0 as                                              (191)

for as < 0

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 48 -

 

Mathematically the physical equations (190) and (197) may be described by equation (192) for all values of as, i.e.

 

Z'i(t) = hF S'u0 as                                                 (192)

 

for  - ¥ < as < ¥

 

With equation (192) the physical inventory system has been converted to a mathematical model where Z'i(t) can change sign and where Z'u(t)

= 0 for all t, cf. equation (189).

 

From equation (181) follows:

 

RL(t) = hR S'u(t)                                                 (193)

 

The definition equation applies:

 

                 t

RL(t) = RL(0) +  ò  Q'i(t) dt                                     (194)

                0

which combined with equation (193) gives:

 

         t

RL(0) +  ò  Q'i(t) dt = hR S'u(t)                                  (195)

        0

or

 

t

ò  Q'i(t) dt = hR S'u(t) - RL(0)                                   (196)

0

If equation (179) is used in equation (196), the following equation is

derived:

 

 t

ò  Q'i(t) dt = hR S'u0 as t + (hR S'u0 - RL(0))                       (197)

0

For t = 0 equation (181) gives:

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 49 -

 

hR = RL(0)/S'u(0)                                                 (198)

 

Using equation (197) together with equation (198) we have:

 

 t

 ò  Q'i(t) dt = hR S'u0 as t                                       (199)

 0

The solution to the integral equation (199) is:

 

Q'i(t) = hR S'u0 as                                                (200)

 

The flow of goods Q'i(t) to the raw materials inventory can now be de- fined by equations (201) and (202):

 

Q'i(t) = hR S'u0 as                                                (201)

for as ³ 0

 

Q'u(t) = - hR S'u0 as                                              (202)

for as < 0

 

Mathematically the physically equations (201) and (202) can be descri-

bed by equation (203) for all values of as, i.e.

 

Q'i(t) = hR S'u0 as                                                (203)

for  - ¥ < as < ¥

 

With equation (203) the physical inventory system has been converted to a mathematica1 model where Q'i(t) can change sign and where Q'u(t) = 0 for all t.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 50 -

 

11.1.3.  Output

Total output T'p(t) is given by:

 

T'p(t) = S'u(t) + Z'i(t)                                           (204)

 

If the ratio ba is here defined as the number of labor hours used per unit of output and the ratio bR as the raw materials consumption per unit of finished goods, the equations, resource balance equations, will apply:

 

a'i(t) = ba T'p(t)                                                (205)

 

V'i(t) = bR T'p(t) + Q'i(t) bR                                      (206)

 

If equation (204) and equation (206) are combined, the following equa- tion is obtained:

 

V'i(t) = bR S'u(t) + bR Z'i(t) + Q'i(t) bR                           (207)

 

If equations (179), (192) and (203) are substituted into equation (207), the following equation is obtained:

 

V'i(t) = bR S'u0 (1 + (hF + hR + t) as)                             (208)

 

Using equations (204), (179) and (192), equation (205) gives:

 

a'i(t) = ba S'u0 (1 + as(t + hF))                                  (208a)

 

11.1.4.  Sales, ingoing payments

Using equations (95), (96) and (97) we obtain payments derived from cash sales:

 

S'i,kon'(t) = p q S'u0 (1 + as t)                                     (209)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 51 -

 

Using equations (88), (95), (98), (99) and (100) we obtain payments derived from debit sales:

 

S'i,deb(t) = p (1 - q) S'u0 (1 + as(t - dD))                           (210)

 

Equations (88), (209) and (210) give:

 

S'i(t) = p q S'u0 (1 + as t) + p (1 - q) S'u0

         (1 + as(t - dD))                                         (211)

or

 

S'i(t) = p S'u0 (1 + as(t - dD(1 - q)))                              (212)

 

11.1.5.  Purchases, outgoing payments

The outgoing payments flow corresponding to cash purchases of raw ma- terials is expressed by means of equations (101), (102), (103) and (208) as

 

V'b,kon(t) = q1 e bR S'u0 (1 + (hF + hR + t)as)                         (213)

 

Credit purchases of raw materials cause an outgoing payments flow which by means of equations (94) (101), (106), (107) and (108) is computed at:

 

V'b(t) = e q1 V'i(t) + (1 - e)q1 V'i (t - dK)                         (214)

 

Equation (214) is transformed by means of equation (208) into:

 

V'b(t) = e q1 bR S'u0(1 + (hF + hR + t) as) +

        (1 - e)q1 bR S'u0(1 + (hF + hR + t - dK)as)                   (215)

 

Equation (215) is reduced to:

 

V'b(t) = q1 bR S'u0(1 + as(hF + hR + t - dK (1 - e)))                (216)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 52 -

 

The total payments flow to purchases of resources is then obtained by using equations (93), (104), (105) and (216):

 

U'b(t) = q2 a'i(t) + q1 bR S'u0(1 + as (hF + hR + t - dK

          (1 - e))) + F'b(t)                                       (217)

 

By substituting equation (208a) into equation (217) the total outgoing payments flow is then given by:

 

U'b(t) = S'u0(q2 ba (1 + as (t + hF)) + q1 bR(1 + as

          (hF + hR + t - dK(1 - e))) + F'b(t)                        (218)

 

11.1.6.  Change in liquidity

The accounting concept, change in liquidity l'(t), here also called cash flow, can then by the use of equations (150), (212) and (218) be given the following form:

 

l'(t) = S'u0(p(1 + as(t - dD(1 - q)))

             - q2 ba (1 + as(t + hF)) - q1 bR(1 + as

               (hF + hR + t - dK(1 - e)))) - F'b(t)                   (219)

 

11.2. Capital tied up in the operating system

Depending on the firm's level of activity capital will be tied up in the operating system. Capital will be tied up in trade accounts payable, raw materials inventories and finished goods inventories as well as accounts receivable (the amounts are indicated with signs).

 

11.2.1.  Trade accounts receivable

The volume of trade accounts receivable is defined by the following equation, equations (88), (95), (98) and (99) being used:

 

           dD

Vdeb(t) =  ò  p(1 - q)S'u(t - x) dx                                (220)

          0

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 53 -

 

In this model it is assumed that equation (179) applies. From this equation combined with (220) follows:

 

                       dD

Vdeb(t) = p(1 - q) S'u0  ò  (1 - as(t - x)) dx                     (221)

                      0

 

The computation of the integral in equation (221) allows equation (221) to be reduced to:

 

Vdeb(t) = p(1 - q) S'u0 dD (1 + as(t - 0.5 dD))                      (222)

 

11.2.2.  Trade accounts payable

The volume of trade accounts payable is defined by the following equation, equations (89), (101), (106) and (107) being used:

 

           dK

Vkre(t) =   ò  q1 bR(1 - e) V'i(t - x)) dx                          (223)

           0

Assuming that sales satisfy equation (179) and that equation (208) applies, equation (223) develops the following expression:

 

                          dK

Vkre(t) = q1 bR(1 - e) S'u0  ò (1 + as(hF + hR + t - x)) dx           (224)

                         0

By computing the integral in equation (224) this equation is reduced to:

 

Vkre(t) = q1 bR(1 - e) S'u0 dK (1 + as(hF + hR + t - 0.5 dK))           (225)

 

l1.2.3  Raw materials inventory

The volume of the raw materials inventory is given by equation (193). The value of the raw materials inventory RL,1(t) satisfies the equation:

 

RL,1(t) = q1 bR RL(t)                                              (226)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 54 -

 

If equations (193) and (179) are substituted into equation (226), we have:

RL,1(t) = q1 bR hR S'u0(1 + as t)                                    (227)

 

11.2.4.  Finished goods inventory

The volume of the finished goods inventory is given by equation (182). The calculated consumption of materials and labor hours per unit of finished goods is given by qF, cf. equation (124). The definition equa- tion applies:

qF = bR q1 + ba q2                                                 (228)

 

The value of the finished goods inventory FL,1(t) satisfies the equati- on:

FL,1(t) = qF FL(t)                                                (229)

 

If equations (182), (179) and (228) are substituted into equation (229), the following expression is obtained:

 

FL,1(t) = (bR q1 + ba q2) hF S'u0(1 + as t)                          (230)

 

11.2.5.  Working capital (tied up in the operating system)

The total capital tied up in the operating system, i.e. the working capital K(t), is through the use of equations (222), (225), (227) and (230) given by:

 

K(t) = Vdeb(t) - Vkre(t) + RL,1(t) + FL,1(t)                         (231)

 

or by substituting into the relevant places

 

K(t) = p(1 - q)S'u0 dD (1 + as(t - 0.5 dD))

       - q1 bR (1 + e)S'u0 dK (1 + as(hF + hR + t - 0.5 dK))

       + q1 bR hR S'u0(1 + as t)

       + (bR q1 + ba q2) hF S'u0(1 + as t)

or

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 55 -

 

 

K(t) = S'u0(1 + as t)(hF (bR q1 + ba q2) + q1 bR hR)

       + p(1 - q) dD S'u0(1 + as(t - 0.5 dD))

       - q1 bR (1 - e) dK S'u0(1 + as(hF + hR + t - 0.5 dK))          (232)

 

12.1.  Operating profit (for accounting purposes)

In the following, functions are established for the computation of operating profit based on accounting theory.

 

The turnover of the firm is obtained by using equations (96), (98), (111), (112) and (113) and is expressed as:

 

S'u,1(t) = p S'u(t)                                                (233)

 

Using equation (233) equation (179) gives:

 

S'u,1(t) = p S'u0(1 + as t)                                         (234)

 

Raw materials consumed corresponding to sales S'u(t) are given by the equation:

 

V'for(t) = q1 bR S'u(t)                                             (235)

 

or by using equation (179):

 

V'for(t) = q1 bR S'u0(1 + as t)                                      (236)

 

The wages paid, time rates, corresponding to sales S'u(t) are given by the equation:

 

a'for(t) = q2 ba S'u(t)                                             (237)

 

or by using equation (179)

 

a'for(t) = q2 ba S'u0(1 + as t)                                      (238)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 56 -

 

 

By using equations (234), (236) and (238) the operating profit O'(t) can now be given the form:

 

O'(t) = S'u,1(t) - V'for(t) - a'for(t) - F'b(t)                        (239)

or

 

O'(t) = S'u0(1 + as t)(p - (q1 bR + q2 ba)) - F'b                    (240)

 

12.2.  Operating profit (computed on the basis of Fig. 1.1)

In this section the operation profit will as an alternative be compu- ted directly on the basis of Fig. 2.1.

 

The costs U'd(t) in connection with sales S'u(t) are given by equation (118). If equations (89), (102), (104), (106), (109), (110), (114), (115), (116), (117), (208) and (208a) are substituted into equation (118), the following equation is developed:

 

U'd(t) = q1 bR S'u0(1 + (hF + hR + t) as)

         + q2 ba S'u0(1 + (hF + t)as) + F'b                          (241)

 

Computed with a plus or minus sign (positive for inventory) the fol- lowing value is added to the raw materials inventory, cf. equation (35):

 

Q'i,1(t) = q1 bR Q'i(t)                                              (242)

 

or equation (203) may be used:

 

Q'i,1(t) = q1 bR hR S'u0 as                                           (243)

 

Here the definition equation for cost prices of raw materials per unit of finished goods has been used:

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 57 -

 

qR = q1 bR                                                       (244)

 

The following value is added to the finished goods inventory, cf. equa- tion (124):

 

Z'i,1(t) = qF Z'i(t)                                               (245)

 

or equation (189) may  be used:

 

Z'i,1(t) = (q1 bR + q2 ba) hF S'u0 as                                 (246)

 

The total value flow to inventories now amounts to, cf. equations (131) and (132):

 

U'tl(t) = q1 bR hR S'u0 as + (q1 bR + q2 ba) hF S'u0 as                  (247)

 

or by reduction

 

U'tl(t) = S'u0 as(q1 bR hR + (q1 bR + q2 ba) hF)                       (248)

 

The total operating profit is obtained by using equations (234), (241) and (248) and is expressed as:

 

O'(t) = S'u(t) - (U'd(t) - U'tl))                                  (249)

 

or by substituting into the right hand side:

 

O'(t) = p S'u0(1 + as t)

        - (q1 bR S'u0(1 + (hF + hR + t) as)

        + q2 ba S'u0(1 + (hF + t) as) + F'b

          - S'u0 as (q1 bR hR + (q1 bR + q2 ba) hF))                   (250)

 

or by reduction:

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 58 -

 

 

O'(t) = S'u0(1 + as t)(p -(q1 bR + q2 ba)) - F'b                    (251)

 

It will be seen that equations (240) and (251) are identical, i.e. a systematic use of Fig. 2.1. gives here the same result as the use of a simple "logical" accounting method.

 

12.2.1.  Operating profit incl. inventory depreciation

If equations (248) and (145) are substituted into equation (147), U'tl,1(t) being computed with a plus or minus sign, the following equation is obtained:

 

B'ln(t) = an S'u0 as (q1 bR hR + (q1 bR + q2 ba) hF)                   (252)

 

The operating profit incl. inventory depreciation is given by equation (149). If equations (251) and (252) are substituted into this equation, the following expression is derived:

 

O'DS(t) = S'u0(1 + as t)(p -(q1 bR + q2 ba)) - F'b

            - an S'u0 as (q1 bR hR + (q1 bR + q2 ba) hF)               (253)

 

or by reduction:

 

O'DS(t) = S'u0((1 + as t)(p -(q1 bR + q2 ba))

            - an as (q1 bR hR + (q1 bR + q2 ba) hF)

          - F'b                                                (253a)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 59 -

 

12.3.1.  Bank loans

This model takes as its starting point that the net working capital tied up K(t) can be given the form:

 

K(t) = K0 + Kinc(t)                                               (254)

 

where K0 is the net working capital tied up at time t = 0, and Kinc(t) is the change in the working capital tied up at time t. It is assumed that equation (255) applies:

 

d Kinc(t)

ŸŸŸŸŸ  = iB(t)                                               (255)

 d t

 

This means that the increase in the capital tied up in the operating system is financed by the bank overdraft.

 

If equation (255) is used together with equation (254), the following equation will also apply:

 

d K(t)

ŸŸŸŸŸ  = iB(t)                                               (255a)

 d t

 

It is assumed that:

 

B(0) = 0                                                        (256)

 

This means that the overdraft amounts to DKK B(0) = 0 at time t = 0.

 

As regards the mathematical model it is pointed out that in equation (255) i'B(t) may be both positive and negative as it is also assumed here that, besides equations such as (152), (153), (154) and (155), the following equation applies:

 

y'B(t) = r'B(t)                                                   (257)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 60 -

 

12.3.2.  Loans (long term)

It is assumed that i'L(t) is discreet, i.e. that

 

i'L(t) = 0 and i'D(t) = 0                                         (258)

 

for all t > 0, apart from certain selected times tq  where, in practi-ce, changes take place in financing conditions, and new investments a- re made. Subject to these assumptions equation (159) may be reduced to

 

i'K(t) = i'B(t)                                                   (259)

 

with the condition i'L,D(t) = 0

 

In close connection with the operational financial possibilities of equations (258) and (259) this model also assumes that equation (260) applies:

 

y'L(t) = r'L(t)                                                   (260)

 

12.3.3.  Investments

Investments are defined by i'(t). It is here assumed that i'(t) = 0 apart from certain times tp corresponding to the forms of investment seen in practice.

 

In this mathematical model equation (162) is changed into:

 

i'(t) = i'L,i(t)                                                  (261)

 

where i'e(t) becomes the quantity, cash flow released, for the following purposes:

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 61 -

 

 

                           New investments

                           Instalments on loans

                           Etc.

 

This change of equation (162) is desirable seen in relation to the possibilities of implementing this mathematical model on a computer.

 

12.4.1.  Interest payments

From equations (165), (166), (167), (257) and (260) the total interest payment is derived:

 

y'B(t) + y'L(t) = rB B(t) + rL L(t)                                (268)

 

where rB is interest rate bank and rL is interest rate lender.

 

12.4.2. Depreciation

Depreciation to tax computation is obtained from equation (164) and is expressed as:

 

d'2(t) = aD D(t)                                                  (263)

 

where aD is the depreciation rate per time period.

 

12.4.3.  Tax payments

From equations (168), (262) and (263) the following equation is deri- ved:

 

f'u(t) = aD D(t) + rB B(t) + rL L(t)                               (264)

 

By using equations (169) and (264) total tax payments are expressed as:

 

H'S,1(t) = s(O'DS(t) - aD D(t) - (rB B(t) + rL L(t)))                 (265)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 62 -

 

12.4.4.  Cashflow released

With the special definition of i'e(t) given in 12.3.3. cash flow relea- sed is defined by:

 

i'e(t) = O'(t) - H'S,1(t) - (y'B(t) + y'L(t))

 

which together with equation (175) gives:

 

i'e(t) = l'(t) + dK(t)/dt - H'S,1(t) - (y'B(t) + y'L(t))

 

If equation (255a) including the related assumption is used here, the following equation is obtained:

 

i'e(t) = l'(t) - H'S,1(t) - (y'B(t) + y'L(t)) + i'B(t)                 (266)

 

or if equations (262) and (265) are used:

 

i'e(t) = l'(t) + i'B(t) - s O'DS(t) + s aD D(t)

         - (1 - s)(rB B(t) + rL L(t))                             (267)

 

By using equations (149) and (174), the following equation is derived from equation (267):

 

i'e(t) = O'(t) - s O'DS(t) + s aD D(t)

         - (1 - s)(rB B(t) + rL L(t))                             (268)

 

If the function O'L(t) is defined by the equation:

O'L(t) = O'(t) - s O'DS(t)                                         (269)

 

O'L(t) may be designated as the profit after tax from the operating system.

 

Equation (268) is now transformed into:

 

i'e(t) = O'L(t)(1 + s aD D(t)/O'L(t)

         - (1 - s)(rB B(t) + rL L(t))/O'L(t)                       (270)

 

It appears from equation (270) that it may be appropriate to define the following managerial ratios:

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 63 -

 

12.4.4.1.  Interest relative

Interest relative is defined by equation (270):

 

                  rB B(t) + rL L(t)

rrel = - (1 - s)   ŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸ                             (271)

                       O'L(t)           

 

rrel can be interpreted as interest payments after tax in relation to profit after tax from the operating system.

 

11.4.4.2.  Depreciation relative

Depreciation relative is defined by equation (270):

 

            aD D(t)

arel =  s    ŸŸŸŸŸŸŸ                                                                                                                   (272)

             O'L(t)

 

arel may be interpreted as the improvement in cash flows after tax as a

result of depreciation in relation to profit after tax from the opera-

ting system.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 64 -

 

13.1. Traditional ratios

In this Chapter some traditional ratios will be computed on the basis of the functional expressions derived in section 12.

 

13.1.1.  Contribution ratio

The contribution ratio DG(t) is defined by the following equation (273):

 

         S'u,1(t) - (U'd,1,1(t) - F'i,2(t))

 DG(t) =   ŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸ                                                        (273)

             S'u,1(t)

 

or by using equations (136), (117), (109) and (110):

 

           O'(t) + F'b

DG(t) =  ŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸ                                                                                                           (274)

             S'u,1(t)

 

13.1.2.  Profit ratio

The profit ratio is defined by the following equation (275):

 

           O'(t)

OG(t) =  ŸŸŸŸŸŸ                                              (275)

          S'u,1(t)

 

13.1.3.  Break-even sales

Break-even sales are defined by equation (276):

 

            F'b

NS'(t) =     ŸŸŸŸŸ                                                                                                                             (276)

           DG(t)

 

i.e. the amount of sales where fixed costs are just covered by sales.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 65 -

 

13.1.4.  Margin of safety

The margin of safety is defined by equation (277):

 

          S'u,1(t) - NS'(t)

SM(t) =  ŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸŸ                                                                      (277)

              S'u,1(t)

 

13.1.5.  Applications, examples

It appears from the above definition equations (274),(275), (276) and (277) that they reflect general financial states in the model Fig. 2.1.

 

Thus, the contribution ratio DG(t) provides a good measure of the cha- racteristics of the change in liquidity l'(t) at a given turnover, i.e.

 

i'(t) = DG(t) S'u,1(t) - F'b                                         (278)

 

this approximation being achieved by using equations (274) and

(174).

 

The profit ratio OG(t) enables the same possibilities of analysis as the contribution ratio (compare equations (274) and (275)). It should be re- membered, however, that DG(t) is constant in time.

 

The profit ratio will be analysed in more detail in connection with the Dupont pyramid.

 

For the purpose of assessing the amount of sales in relation to a mini- mum level, two rough measures are available, the margin of safety and break-even sales. It is important to bear in mind that these ratios are partial and narrowly defined for operations research purposes.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 66 -

 

13.2. Dupont pyramid. Fig. 13.1. shows the Dupont pyramid containing the ratio, rate of return A. It will be seen that the Dupont pyramid con- sists of two major components: Income Statement and Assets on the basis of which the rate of return A by definition is computed as:

 

      O

A  =    ŸŸŸ                                                                                                                                                   (279)

      T

 

Equation (279) can be transformed into

 

      O      S

A  =    ŸŸŸ   ŸŸŸ                                                                                                                                  (280)

      S      T

 

With the definitions profit ratio OG and the turnover rate of assets AS, which are both mathematical functions for operations research pur- poses, equation (280) is given the form:

 

A = OG AS                                                       (281)

 

In connection with the computation of total assets T it is essential to note that for accounting purposes it is difficult to determine the exact value of the assets. How is, for example, the value of production machi- nery to be valued? The rate of return defined by equation (279) is thus a rough measure of the financial efficiency of the production faciliti- es.

 

It is pointed out that equation (281) has the same resulting informati- ve contents as equation (279). In equation (281) an extra variable in the form of sales S has been put in. This ratio technique, which has been adopted by, among others, Bela Gold, will be considered in greater detail in the following pages.

 

 

- 67 -

               

 

 

Figure  13.1

 

The Dupont Pyramid

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 68 -

 

13.2.1.  Ratio mathematics, general

For the ratio U given by equation (282):

 

        y

U  =       ŸŸŸ                                                                                                                                             (282)

        x

 

where y and x are system variable and/or system state functions, finan- cial or physical, the general function given by equation (283) applies in the same system:

 

        y      x1            xn       xn+1

U  =       ŸŸŸ  ( ŸŸŸ   -  -  -  -     ŸŸŸ ) ŸŸŸ                                                    (283)

        x1     x2              xn+1      x

 

In equation (283) xi for i = 1, - - - -, n is an arbitrary quantity of system variable and/or system state functions.

 

If we define the ratio G1 = y/x1, Gi = xi/xi+1 for i = 1, - - - , n and Gn = xn+1/x, equation (283) may be given the equivalent form:

 

U = G1 G2 G3 - - - - Gn                                           (284)

 

This is exactly the ratio technique forming the basis of the computati- on of the rate of return by the methods described in Section 13.2. (By the inserted variable S in equation (280) or by the product method in equation (281)).

 

A look at Bela Gold's work on managerial ratios will show that equati- ons (282), (283) and (284) constitute the theoretical contents of Bela Gold's application of ratios. It will be seen

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 69 -

 

that exactly the assumptions underlying equation (283) are the reason why the equation is not unique for a given system as regards the effect of the individual ratios on U. Thus, these effects can only provide cer- tain indications as to states in the system under study.

 

As a result of the above comments on the lack of uniqueness of a number of factors in a given development of a ratio, S, OG and AS are encircled by a broken line in Fig. 13.1.

 

The above equations provide the theoretical background of the uncertain- ty found in the literature on depiction of the Dupont pyramid. Thus, this pyramid is often shown without the S, OG and AS areas encircled by broken lines. The Dupont pyramid has a very simple memo-technical struc- ture. This structure consists of

 

 

 

The Dupont pyramid is a kind of rough aid for analysis purposes rather than a basic scientific figure with fundamental contents, cf. above.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 70 -

 

Conclusion

The literature on the whole area of management, accountancy, manageri-

al economics and ratios has been reviewed. Only one source, lit. 30,

has been found suitable for a more detailed analysis in relation to

the management subject discussed: Managerial ratios.

 

As shown in Chapter A, S. Eilon's work takes as its starting point the

rate of return and defines a set of equations which under different

circumstances describe the effect of the rate of return. The assumpti-

ons underlying S. Eilon's equations are considered more closely, and

two weaknesses are found in the application of these equations. Eilon

uses the concept average variable costs, which is a generally applied

concept in tradi  tional managerial economics. Eilon uses also an empi- rically based equation for the relationships between the sales activity and the funds tied up in the operating system. These two assumptions have given rise to the need for a continued theoretical development of the described mathematical functions as well as graphical models.

 

In Chapter B a graphical analytical business model is developed for

the purpose of giving management a picture of fundamental characteri-

stics in the business within bookkeeping, accountancy, managerial eco-

nomics and taxation. In Chapter B the mathematical functional expres-

sion for inventory depreciation is developed, equation (149), to form

the basis of the presentation of the relationship between O'DS, B'ln and O' in Fig. 2.1.

 

On the basis of the general graphical model with related mathematical

functions the mathematical analytical model is developed in Chapter C.

This model includes a number of definitions of general mathematical

functions as well as related parameters so that the developed functio- nal expressions give an analytical mathematical description of general-

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 71 -

 

concepts relating to book keeping, accountancy, managerial economics and taxation in the business on the basis of common input parameters, inclu- ding time as an explicit parameter.

 

Among the new functional expressions developed in Chapter C special

attention is called to the definition equation (174) together with the

condition equation (259) both of which form the basis of the develop-

ment of the general expression for cash flow released, see equation

(270). For assessments of the soundness of cash flow released, two ra-

tios have been developed, interest relative and depreciation relative,

see equati6n (271) and equation (272).

 

On the basis of the developed mathematical functions the traditional

ratios are presented in an analytical mathematical form as a function

of, among other things, time. To facilitate analysis, the complex func- tional expressions found have not been included in Chapter C, Section 13.

 

The Dupont pyramid, which forms the basis of the so-called "rate-of-

return philosophy", is in Fig. 13.1. divided into its basic components: Income Statement and Assets. The elements encircled by broken lines in Fig. 13.1., which are often omitted in representations, include the profit ratio and the turnover rate of assets. The development of the general ratio formula given by equation (283) has proved that the profit ratio and the turnover rate of assets are arbitrary accounting ratios.

 

With equation (283) and equation (284) the mathematical basis of the

computation of the rate of return and of Bela Gold's empirically deve-

loped ratio technique, lit. 40, has been developed.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

- 72 -

 

 

BIBLIOGRAPHY

 

1.    Ahlmark, Dan:

         Produkt - investering - finansiering

         Stockholm 1974

 

2.    Andersen, A. Geel:

         Investeringsteori. Partiel investeringsplanlægning under

         sikkerhed

         Copenhagen, The School of Economics and Business

         Administration 1973

 

3.    Ansoff, H. Iqor:

         Strategisk planlægning

         Copenhagen 1972

 

4.    Arvidson, Herbert:

         Foeretagsvaerdering, 3.

         Stockholm 1978

 

5.    Arwidz, Olof & Allan T. Maim:

         Planeringssystem - en ram foer analys och konstruktion

         Lund 1973

 

6.    Asztely Sandor:

         Investeringsplanering

         Stockholm 1973

 

7.    Bacharach, Michael:

         Economics and the theory of games

         London 1976

 

8.    Baglini, Norman A:

         Risk management in international corporations

         New York 1971

 

9.    Baker, A.J.:

         Investment, valuation and the managerial theory of firm

         Famborough 1978

 

10.   Bannoch, Graham:

         Smaller business in Britain and Germany

         London 1976

 

11.   Bergienut, P. och M. Hentzel:

         Investering

         Stockholm 1976

 

 

 

.

- 73 -

 

12.   Bjarke, Ø. and 0.1. Franksen:

         System structures in engineering. Economic design and

         production

         Lyngby The Technical University of Denmark, AMT 1978

 

13.   Børsen PP3:

         Erhvervenes og det offentliges udviklingsmønster fren til

         1982.

         Copenhagen 1977

 

14.   Coates, C. Robert:

         Investment strategy

         London 1978

 

15.   Coyle, R.G.:

         Management system dynamics

         London 1977

 

16.   Cleland, David I. & William R. King:

         Management. A system approach

         New York 1972

 

17.   Correa, Hector:

         Integrated economic accounting Lexington,

         Mass. 1977

 

18.   Danielsson, Albert:

         Foeretagsekonomi. Begreppsbildning och terminologie

         Stockholm 1976

 

19.   Danielsson, Albert:

         Foeretagsekonomi - en oeversikt

         Lund 1975

 

20.   Danielsson, Albert:

         On measurement and analysis of standard costs

         Stockholm 1963

 

21.   Dansk Management Center:

         Inflationsregnskaber

         Copenhagen 1978

 

22.   Danø, Sven:

         Introduktion til levetidsproblemer i investeringplanlægningen

         Copenhagen 1978

 

23.   Dam-Jensen, Erik m.fl.

         Regnskab og økonomi

         Copenhagen 1977

 

 

.

- 74 -

 

 

24.   Donaldson, Gordon:

         Strategy for financial mobility

         Boston 1969

 

25.   Donaldson, Peter & Jim Clifford:

         Economy and decision making

         London 1977

 

26.   Dullum, K:

         Virksomhedens økonomiske styring 1 & 2

         Copenhagen 1975

 

27.   Eckholm, Bo-Goeran:

         Planering foer finansiell handlingsberedskap

         Helsingfors 1977

 

28.   EDB-rådet:

         EDB, ledelse og økonomi

         Copenhagen 1977

 

29.   Eilon S. and Phocas-Cosmetatos G:

         Analysis of profitability components. Proc. Euro II, Second

         European Congress on Operations Research pp

         143-147  ...... 1976

 

30.   Eilon, Samuel & Cosmetatos, G.P.:

         A profitability  model for tactical planning

         OMEGA, Vol. 5, No. 6 1977

 

31.   Eilon, S., Gold Bela, and Soesan J.:

         Applied productivity analysis for industry Pergamon Press,

         Oxford 1976

 

32.   Eliasson, Gunnar:

         Business economic planning

         Stockholm 1976

 

33.   Fabryky, W.J. and G.J. Thuesen:

         Economic decision analysis

         Copenhagen 1974

 

34.   Falster, P.:

         Graph-oriented production models in APL Lyngby,

         The Technical University of Denmark, 1977

 

35.   Fiehn, Peter:

         Produktionsstyring

         Lyngby, The Technical University of Denmark, AMT 1978

 

 

.

- 75 -

 

36.   Fog,Bjarke:

         Mikroøkonomi

         Copenhagen 1977

 

37.   Forrester, Jay W.:

         Industrial Dynamics

         Cambridge, Mass. 1977

 

38.   Gitman, Lawrence J.:

         Principles of managerial finance

         New York l976

 

39.   Gold, Bela:

         Explorations in managerial economics

         London 1971

 

40.   Gold, Bela:

         Technological change. Economics, management and environment

         Oxford 1975

 

41.   Grant, Alexander Thomas Kingdom:

         Economic uncertainty and financial structure

 

42.   Greene, Mark R.:

         Decision analysis for risk management

         New York 1977

 

43.   Grubbstroem, Robert W.:

         Besluts- och spelteori med tillaempninger

         Lund 1977

 

44.   Gunst, Jens & Niels Lauritsen;

         Planlaegning og prioritering

         Copenhagen 1977

 

45.   Hailes, William D. & Raymond T. Hubbard:

         Small business management New York 1977

 

46.   Hansen, Erik m.fl.:

         Langtidsstyring

         Copenhagen 1974

 

47.   Hartley, W.C.F.:

         Likviditetsstyringens ABZ

         Institut for lederskab og 1ønsomhed

         Copenhagen 1978

 

48.   Hemming, Torn;

         Multiobjective decision making under certainty

         Stockholm 1978

 

.

- 76 -

 

 

49.   Industrirådet:

         Industriens Økonomi

         Copenhagen 1977

 

50.   Industriens Utredningsinstitut;

         IUI's långtidsbedoemning 1976

         Stockholm 1977

 

51.   Jacobsen, Vagn Thorsgaard:

         Valg af strategi og beslutning under usikkerhed

         Copenhagen 1971

 

52.   Jensen, A.:

         Planlægning i uvished

         Lyngby, The Technical University of Denmark,

         IMSOR 1977

 

53.   Jørgensen, Kj. Arnth:

         Strategisk ledelse i mellemstore virksomheder

         Danmarks Erhvervsfond 1977

 

54.   Jørgensen, Niels Lihn:

         Dynamisk input - output teori

         Copenhagen 1977

 

55.   Kallio, Markku:

         Corporate planning model

         Helsinki 1977

 

56.   Keeney, Ralph L. & Howard Raiffa:

         Decisions with multiple objectives

         New York 1976

 

57.   Keloharjn, Raimo:

         Corporate modelling in system dynamics

         Helsinki 1977

 

58.   Kenessey, Zoltan:

         Process of economic planning

         New York 1978

 

59.   Kline,John B.:

         Management audit for small manufacturers

         Wash. D.C. 1977

 

60.   Kohn, Mervin:

         Dynamic managing. Principles, process, practice

         California 1977

 

 

.

- 77 -

 

 

61.   Levy, Ham  & Marshall Sarnst:

         Capital investment and financial decisions

         Englewood Cliffs. N.J. 1978

 

62.   Lichtenberg, S.:

         Projektplanlægning

         Lyngby, The Technical University of Denmark 1978

 

63.   Lin, Steven:

         Conference on externalities, 1974. Southern Illinois

         University. Theory and measurement of economic externalities.

         New York 1976

 

64.   Liung, Birger:

         Investeringsbedoeinning

         Stockholm 1978

 

65.   Linestone, Harold A. & Devendra Sahal:

         Technological substitution: Forecasting techniques and

         applications

         New York 1976

 

66.   Longenecher, Justin G.:

         Essentials of management

         Illinois 1977

 

67.   Lorange, Peter and others:

         Strategic planning systems

         Englewood Cliffs. N.J. 1977

 

68.   MacKinzie, R. Alec..

         New time management methods for you and your staff

         London 1975

 

69.   Martel, Jean Marc:

         Adaptive strategies for a replacement problem

         Louvain Univ. 1975

 

70.   McLean, Ephraim R. & John V. Soden:

         Strategic planning for MIS

         New York 1977

 

71.   Monks, Joseph G.:

         Operations management. Theory and problems

         New York 1977

 

72.   Muhlemann, A.P. m.fl.

         On portfolio modelling in multiple criteria situations

         under uncertainty

         Manchester 1977

.

- 78 -

 

 

73.   Mulvaney,J.E. & C.W. Mann:

         Practical business models

         London 1978

 

74.   Neergaard, Peter:

         På basis af - - - - -

         Thesis for the licentiate, The Copenhagen School of

         Economics and Business Administration 1977

 

75.   O'Connor, Rochelle:

         Planning under uncertainty

         New York 1978

 

76.   Olsen, M. Kolbe:

         Salgets planlægning og organisation

         Copenhagen 1977

 

77.   Papps, Ivy & Willie Henderson:

         Models and economic theory

         London 1977

 

78.   Parker, J.E.S.:

         Economics of innovation

         London 1978

 

79.   Petersen, Anders:

         Konstruktion af systemer for økonomisk styrinq

         Jern- og Metalindustriens Sammenslutning

         Copenhagen 1976

 

80.   Petersen, Eskild:

         Målsætning i virksomheden

         Copenhagen 1977

 

81.   Peterson, Rein & Edward, A. Silver:

         Decision Systems for inventory management and production

         planning

         New York 1978

 

82.   Pfeffer, Irving:

         Insurance and economic theory Illinois 1956

 

83.   Pitchford, John D. & Stephen, J. Turnovsky:

         Applications of control theory to economic analysis

         Amsterdam 1977

 

84.   Ramstroem, Dick:

         Docentur I foeretagsekonomi

         Uppsala 1977

 

.

- 79 -

 

 

85.   Riis, Jens Ove:

         Design of management Systems

         Copenhagen 1978

 

86.   Rasmussen,Flemming:

         Eksempler på partiel investeringsplanlaegning

         Copenhagen 1977

 

87.   Rasmussen, Flemming:

         Partiel investeringsplanlaegning

         Lyngby, The Technical university of Denmark, IMSOR 1978

 

88.   Rasmussen, G.:

         Produktionsfunktioners anvendelse pA virksomhedsniveau

         Lyngby, The Technical university of Denmark, AMT .....

 

89.   Sandberg, Åke m.fl.:

         Ny foeretagsekonomi

         Stockholm 1978

 

90.   Samuels, J.M. and Wilkes, F.M.:

         Management of company finance

         London 1975

 

91.   Simon, Herbert A.:

         New science of management decision

         Englewood Cliffs., N.J. 1977

 

92.   Siegwart, Hans:

         Produktentwicklung in der industriellen Unternehmunq

         Bern 1974

 

93.   Sofka, Michael:

         Marketingstrategie fuer ein neues Produkt

         Diessenhofen 1971

 

94.   Stemp, Isay:

         Corporate growth strategies

         New York 1970

 

95.   Steuch, Axel:

         Finansiel planlægning

         Copenhagen 1977

 

96.   Stone, Merlin:

         Product planning

         New York 1976

 

 

 

.

- 80 -

 

 

97.   Sørensen, Finn C.:

         Artikier om kreditvurdering og regnskabsanalyse

         Copenhagen 1978

 

98.   Siegel, Paul:

         Strategic planning of management information systems

         New York 1975

 

99.   Steers, Richard M.:

         Organizational effectiveness

         California 1977

 

100.  Struntz, Harald:

         Langfristige Personalplanung auf der Grundlage von

         Investitionsmodellen

         Wiesbaden 1976

 

101.  Sveriges Mekanfoerbund:

         Nyckeltal i produktionen

         Stockholm 1978

 

102.  Sveriges Mekanfoerbund:

         Produktivitetsmaetning

         Stockholm 1978

 

103.  Tamari, M.:

         Financial ratios

         London 1978

 

104.  Thage, Bent & Jørn Holdt:

         Input - output prismodel for Danmark

         Copenhagen 1976

 

105.   Twiss, Brian C.:

          Managing technological innovation

          London 1976

 

106.   Wagner, Harvey M.:

          Principles of operations research with applications to

          managerial decisions

          Prentice-Hall. Inc 1975

 

107.   White, D.J.:

          Fundamentals of decision theory

          New York 1976

 

108.  Williams, C. Arthur & Richards M. Hems:

          Risk management and insurance

          New York 1976

 

.

- 81 -

 

 

109.  Wong, Kenneth Kin:

          Risk analysis and control. A guide for DP managers

          Manchester 1977

 

110.  Worre, Zakken:

          Vejledning i driftsbudgettering i den mindre virksomhed

          Copenhagen 1974

 

111.  Worre, Zakken:

          Vejledning i likviditetsbudgettering i den

          mindre virksomhed I og II

          Copenhagen 1973

 

112.  Young, Jerrald F.:

          Decision making for small business in management

          New York 1977